+
 
For the best experience, open
m.thewire.in
on your mobile browser or Download our App.

The Limitations of India’s Obsession With Short-Term GDP Growth Data

economy
Most GDP calculations work primarily on ‘estimates’ made with ‘extrapolations’ from growth-driving sectoral trends based on real-time trends. The real question is whether these ‘extrapolations’ end up reflecting India’s actual economic situation during a period of time. 
A focus on short-term trends can lead to confusion and calls for a more comprehensive evaluation of India's economic situation. Credit: PTI/File photo

This piece was first published on The India Cable – a premium newsletter from The Wire & Galileo Ideas – and has been republished here. To subscribe to The India Cable, click here.

In a recent column, former chief economic advisor Arvind Subramanian and Josh Felman provided an assessment based on the recent GDP growth numbers, and argued for the need to look at the “production side” of growth evaluation measurement, while studying for discrepancies observed between the nominal and real growth figures.

Their analysis showed a divergence when the real growth numbers were positioned against the nominal numbers. The nominal figures track the real numbers until the first half of FY23 but then decline by a whopping 14% over the past three quarters. They say that this is “a narrative of an economy which has decelerated sharply to very modest levels”.

The finance ministry was quick to respond. Justifying its methodology for calculating GDP, the ministry argued that India’s real GDP growth was 7.8% year-on-year in the first quarter of FY24, based on income or production approach.

As per the expenditure approach of GDP measurement, it would have been lower, it said. “So, a balancing figure–statistical discrepancy–is added to the expenditure approach estimate. These discrepancies are both positive and negative. Over time, they wash out.”

What (Indian) GDP fails to measure and account for

In a 2007 essay, this author discussed some of the fundamental limitations of GDP as an indicator of growth in India and much of the developing world, where an unorganised and informal workforce obtains. It might be worth recalling some of those arguments here.

First, GDP measures the total monetary value of final goods and services produced within the domestic territory of the country over a period of time. While significant methodological advancements have been made in GDP accounting at both the national and global levels, one critical limitation of both GDP and GNP (Gross National Product) is that they only value outputs at market prices. In countries like India, most economic activities occur outside the market and the value of their outputs needs to be calculated. This is called the “imputed” value.

Subsistence farmers consume the food they produce, and economists often fail to estimate the quantity of produce and impute market values to it. For homeowners, economists usually fail to impute the value of the “dwelling services” involved (as if the house owners are paying the rents at market rates to themselves).

Moreover, all non-market transactions or output is missed out from the official GDP accounting process. Its value isn’t even imputed. Look at India’s massive informal sector, which was hit worst by demonetisation, the hurried implementation of the GST and the curfew-style lockdown.

Second, income measures like GNP, which accounts for the incomes of all residents of a country, fail to realistically represent the living standards of people. An optimal standard of living is vital for measuring developmental progress. However, with GDP and GNP, you can get a perspective on living standards only by accounting for total and average monetary income (as done by per capita income).

Even if we are rational as consumers, the existence of positional goods (a concept coined first by the economist Fred Hirsch and explained as a good which is only valued by the possessor because it’s not possessed by others) in any country, makes income an unreliable gauge of true living standard. Positional goods have value because only a small proportion of potential consumers can have them. This means, even if our income increases (with an 8% GDP growth rate), we may still be unable to acquire houses in prime locations, a good education or access to top jobs. This point is connected to explaining India’s slowing productivity rate, exacerbating the skill gap and worsening unemployment.

Third, the distribution of income amongst and within households or economic classes is not captured by GDP data. For most studies measuring and accounting for trends in income inequality, survey methods based on consumer spending and consumption behaviour are used and relied upon.

Fourth, one of the most important limitations of GDP is that much of the work done by people today remains under-measured or largely unaccounted for. Despite an overwhelming emphasis on it across social sciences, the value of work – a definitive condition of humanity in most of our history – is sporadically covered by modern economics as a subject beyond the income it generates from the hours recorded at work.

Fifth, on inflation, as explained more recently, India’s notoriously high retail price inflation has a number of additional causal factors (read the evidence on seller’s inflation in the fuel-price-anchored inflation level) that find little focus or explanation. This counter-intuitively impacts the possibility of correctly diagnosing ‘real’ growth trends (which are inflation-adjusted). If inflation or deflation measurement itself lacks a robust causal mechanism for measurement and validation, growth trends will showcase divergences between their real and nominal values.

Methods in mainstream growth economics also fail to incorporate the effect of some of the techno-capitalistic advancements made like the role of the internet, telecommunications, and so on in shaping the productive capabilities of people in modern economies and the nature of work itself.

In summation, most GDP calculations – much like most economic indicator-based analysis – work primarily on ‘estimates’ made with ‘extrapolations’ from growth-driving sectoral trends based on real-time trends. The real question is whether these ‘extrapolations’ end up reflecting India’s actual economic situation during a period of time.

Intersectional mechanisms to validate growth figures require focus and empirical scrutiny that is independent from political and partisan bias. Such assessments with historical context and time-series validations may help the government to stop its obsessions with popularising/justifying short-term trends that may do little to clarify but may rather confuse more within its own ranks-and the critics too.

Deepanshu Mohan is Professor of Economics and Director, Centre for New Economics Studies, O.P. Jindal Global University. He is a Visiting Professor to the School of International Development and Global Studies, University of Ottawa, Canada, and an Honorary Research Fellow, Birkbeck College, University of London this Fall.

Make a contribution to Independent Journalism
facebook twitter